According to David
Harvey, “Neoliberalism is in the first instance a theory of political economic
practices that proposes that human well-being can best be advanced by
liberating individual entrepreneurial freedoms and skills within an
institutional framework characterized by strong private property rights, free
markets, and free trade… [and] …holds that the social good will be maximized by
maximizing the reach and frequency of market transactions, and it seeks to
bring all human action into the domain of the market” (Harvey 2006:2-3). But
what does this mean? What could be wrong
with “liberating individual entrepreneurial freedoms,” owning property,
engaging freely in markets and trade? Why would people want to be regulated and
‘controlled,’ as opposed to having the universality of “the market”
effortlessly decide (or guide) things for us?
Much of modern – and especially Western society sees these buzzwords as
positive things that allow people to work hard and create their own lives. However, this narrative is only a very small
part of what neoliberalism entails.
According to
Anthropologist Tejaswini Ganti, neoliberalism is highly complex and has many
meanings, but she claims that “the concept has four main referents: (a) a set
of economic reform policies that some political scientists characterize as the
“D-L-P formula,” which are concerned with the deregulation of the economy, the
liberalization of trade and industry, and the privatization of state-owned
enterprises; (b) a prescriptive development model that defines very different
political roles for labor, capital, and the state compared with prior models,
with tremendous economic, social, and political implications; (c) an ideology
that values market exchange as “an ethic in itself, capable of acting as a
guide to all human action and substituting for all previously held ethical
beliefs;” and (d) a mode of governance that embraces the idea of the
self-regulating free market, with its associated values of competition and
self-interest, as the model for effective and efficient government (Ganti
2014:91).
But what does this
mean in real-life terms today? For this I take a historical approach using
David Harvey’s Conditions of
Postmodernity (1990) where he keenly examines how neoliberalism develops throughout
the twentieth century. Harvey starts his narrative in 1914 with Henry Ford’s
car assembly line where he pays a very high wage of $5 for an 8-hour workday.
According to Harvey, it was not this process that was so revolutionary, rather
it was Ford’s “vision.” Ford seemingly understood that mass production meant
mass consumption, which ushered in a new “politics of labour control and
management… a new kind of rationalized, modernist, and populist democratic
society” (Harvey 1990:125-6). Ford
believed that this wage would offer him the best and most committed workers,
and also provide them with the money and leisure time to consume both his and
other goods (Harvey 1990:126). This ideology ushered in a period of general
progress in advanced industrial societies. Using Keynesian economic policies
and theories, the power of the state had increased in conjunction with the
development of the social welfare state; and within which labor rights were
protected and advanced by strong unions and the structural aspects of Fordist
production practices helped foster community involvement and cohesive and
organized labor groups (Harvey 1990).
According to
Harvey, this process changed greatly in the early to mid-1970s. Following the oil and economic crises during
that decade, there was a massive push for deregulation and more flexible modes
of production. Fordist-era production had been based on building single
factories where companies could produce an entire line of goods from start to
finish in one place. As per the nascent neoliberal ideology, this rigidity did
not allow businesses to react nimbly to shocks in the market, recessions,
supply chain problems, and labor issues. Any problems the economy faced were
also said to be exacerbated by increasingly inadequate Fordist methods of
macroeconomic management (Harvey 1990).
During this time, Harvey points to a political economic shift that he
labels “flexible accumulation,” and is “marked by a direct confrontation with
the rigidities of Fordism. [Flexible accumulation] rests on flexibility with
respect to labour processes, labour markets, products, and patterns of
consumption. It is characterized by the emergence of entirely new sectors of
production, new ways of providing financial services, new markets, and, above
all, greatly intensified rates of commercial, technological, and organizational
innovation” (Harvey 1990:147).
The key component
that Harvey points to within this process is an acceleration of the “time-space
compression” modern society experienced over the last several centuries. With
technological advances in communications, satellites, transportation, etcetera,
the world had “shrunk” and it became easier to communicate, ship to, or even be
in, faraway places quickly (Harvey 1990). This meant that the era of a fixed
factory with local workers producing an entire product, morphed into a process
where companies simply rented production facilities in cheap locations (such as
China) for a month, produced a product or part of a product, continued or
finished the production in a separate facility, and then sold it in whatever
market they could make the most money. This principle started what has been
called the “race to the bottom,” in which developing countries offer the most
“business friendly” incentives (such as tax breaks, deregulation, decreased
labor power and oversight, etc.) to companies that locate production within
their borders. This heightened global competition between states as companies
evaluated entire supply and production chains from raw materials to market to find
the cheapest places to procure and produce each individual component and
product. Companies started locating their production where they had the lowest
costs to market, specifically the lowest overhead costs per worker (basically
less pay, less benefits, less safety at work, etc). Countries started
deregulating their labor industries to attract more businesses. This weakened
labor power and unions, and ushered in higher levels of structural
un/underemployment and an expansion of part-time contract work. According to
Harvey, all of this led to an incredible fragmenting of society and social
connections, severing community ties, creating more individualized populations,
and decreasing the capacity for workers and individuals to organize politically
and economically (Harvey 1990:153).
Building upon
Harvey’s discussion of the shift to flexible modes of accumulation, this
ideology is also traced to the Mont Pelerin Society (Ganti 2014) founded in
1947, and the “Chicago school” (of economic thought) led by Fredrich Hayek and
Milton Friedman in the 1960s and 1970s and built upon neoclassical economic
theory. The new form of this ideology was then instituted politically by Ronald
Reagan and Margaret Thatcher in the 1980s, and globalized by technocratic
regimes such as the figurative “Washington Consensus” in the 1990s. It is
during these decades that John Gledhill (2006:332) believes neoliberalism as an
ideology and global capitalism become intertwined, and spread throughout the
world economy.
If we go back to Ganti’s four common
themes we can see the outcomes of these policies on the ground, and that the
state is still very much involved. Neoliberal policy initiatives deregulate,
liberalize, and privatize economies; redefine political roles for labor,
capital, and the state in marked ways; believe that an ethic of market exchange
is capable of guiding all human action; and that a self-regulating free market
(based on competition and self-interest) becomes the model for effective and
efficient government. However, this was not in the traditional welfarist and
Keynesian tradition, for the State loosens (or alters) its control by actively
deregulating business climates, extricating itself from the market as much as
possible, yet wholly redirecting state power toward allowing a “friendly
business and regulatory climate” and within markets (Gledhill 2006:333). Neoliberal
ideology is not about simply providing free markets as neoclassical ideology
prescribed, but rather pushed for a “concerted political effort and
organization” of society that was the most advantageous for businesses (Ganti
2014:92).
State services became the domain of
non-profit actors, previously state-owned companies were privatized to allow
for individual ownership and control, and labor practices and subsidies
actually aided businesses beyond simply freeing up markets. The core tenets of
economic society still involved individuals acting as rational actors working
toward maximizing individual and corporate gains, but now businesses interests
were placed above the interests of states, communities, and individuals (think
of Harvey’s flexible accumulation and a more fragmented, individualist society
as per Hayek and Rand’s positions, but that actively incentivized business
interests above individual people’s interests). This was a decided divergence
from Adam Smith’s belief that business leaders
should not be listened to in matters of politics for this would be
taking advice “from an order of men whose interest
is never exactly the same with that of the public, who have generally an
interest to deceive and even to oppress the public, and who accordingly have,
upon many occasions, both deceived and oppressed it” (Smith 1991:220).
This shift towards business interests led
to increased competition among some individuals, groups, and companies, but not
those companies with close ties to neoliberal and Western governments (think
World-Systems and Accumulation by Dispossession). This process of
neoliberalization lead to increased inequality locally among individuals, but
also globally among people and countries, and – while said to be aimed at
empowering individuals – predominantly empowered the wealthy and “well situated”
by increasing their economic and political power (as well as their profits). To
Gledhill, neoliberalism is “the ideology of the period in which capitalism
deepened to embrace the production of social life itself, seeking to
commoditize the most intimate of human relations and the production of identity
and personhood” (Gledhill 2006:340). It is within neoliberalism that human
interactions cease to be human interactions and (as every component of human
interaction is brought within the scope of the market) are institutionalized as
market interactions.
However, there are
some complexities within this process. The work of Andrea Meuhlebach (2012) shows
that despite David Harvey and John Gledhill’s observations positing the
fragmentation of neoliberalizing societies as wholly negative, this
fragmentation also creates (or forefronts) individual subjects’ longing for
(and enactments of) a human morality that is intent on caring for others
(Meuhlebach 2012). Her work shows that people in northern Italy volunteered and
cared for less fortunate people both in spite of, and buttressed by, neoliberal
policies. Meuhlebach’s analysis however, based on ethnographic work with
caregivers, focuses primarily on everyday individuals and the elderly. As a
result she seemingly ignores the obvious critique of the very divisive neoliberal
ideology used by elites and capitalists that causes the need for this voluntary
human caring in the first place. Still, her research complicates our analysis
of neoliberal societies by showing a connectivity and caring that others claim
is minimized in neoliberal society.
Neoliberalism is
further complicated by Jamie Peck and Adam Tickell’s work showing the
localization of experiences with neoliberalism, which illuminate “local
neoliberalisms [that] are embedded within larger within larger networks and
structures of neoliberalism” (Peck and Tickell 2002). Kingfisher and Maskovsky critique neoliberalism
for its use as a thing that is often wielded to singularly explain or explore
anywhere in the world or any type of experience. They see neoliberalism as an
experiential and contextualized moment that happens in a multitude of ways in a
multitude of places, and that each experience should be seen as singular, even
if patterns can be recognized (Kingfisher and Maskovsky 2008). Within this
synthesis, Kingfisher and Maskovsky attempt to:
“move beyond the view of neoliberalism as a unitary external structural force — conceived either as a set of economic policies or discourses — that bears down on states, civil society institutions, populations or individuals, whose agency is conceived narrowly in terms of either accommodation or resistance. This structure/agency binary, while oft-times noble in its emphasis on resistance, nonetheless risks describing neoliberalism ‘as something that is perhaps more powerful and all-encompassing than it really is, ignoring in the process its contradictions, fractures, partialities, contingencies, and both dialectics with and determinations by other social forces.’” They seek specifically to “interrogate, situate and problematize (rather than overstate) neoliberalism’s power to reshape the world” (Kingfisher and Maskovsky 2008:119).
As if that does
not disjoint our understandings enough, Simon Springer (2014) believes that we
are actually moving into a postneoliberal world. He claims that since the economic crisis of
2008 there has been great pushback and protest surrounding neoliberal
institutions and politics, and that many of the major industrialized countries
in the world reinstituted Keynsian economic practices, and therefore increased
state intervention (Springer 2014:2). His analysis points toward a global
society moving towards something new, though he is not willing to say this explicitly,
as amid the multitudes of non neoliberal practices, neoliberal patterns still
dominate global political economic ideologies.
This is especially true at the level of governance and business
decisions – places where capitalism carries profound power. Hence, while in the
streets, neoliberalism may be seen as a disaster; but to those in positions of
power – those who are making decisions about shaping our political, economic,
and social futures (and are being rewarded by the status quo) – neoliberalism
is very beneficial and therefore worth continuing. Yet still, the fact that there is discussion
of other ways of organizing society shows that communities and individuals who
are not wealthy (or “successful”) are fighting against this version of
capitalism and a greater rule of their own lives.
No comments:
Post a Comment